|
||
|
||
Fundamental flaws in the European project The fatal defect in the eurozone project was that it was informed by a neoliberal view of leaving policy entirely to market forces, say George Irvin and Alex Izurieta. EURO notes and coins were launched with great expectations in January 2001, the product of a decade of negotiations between the original participants, all 12 of whom were signatories of the Maastricht Treaty of 1993. For nearly a decade the experiment appeared to prosper. A common currency, combined with the 'borderless travel' agreed earlier between Schengen area signatories, appeared to turn Europe from a disparate group of neighbouring states into a seamless giant whose combined population and gross domestic product (GDP) placed it at par with the United States. Today, in contrast,
the euro is under attack from the financial markets, with In essence, our argument is that the euro, aimed at removing nominal exchange rate fluctuations in a wide free-trade area, was informed by a neoliberal view of leaving policy entirely to market forces. In consequence, by way of its specific design, it removed three essential policy instruments at once from the domain of national policymaking - exchange rate management, monetary policy and fiscal policy - and it intrinsically weakened labour and welfare policy. While the loss of exchange rate flexibility for individual countries is part of the common currency construct, exchange rate management of the euro for the EA as a whole was made to fall outside the remit of the European Central Bank (ECB). Nor was the ECB allowed to act as 'banker' for the EA in a manner analogous to the Bank of England (BOE) or the US Federal Reserve since it cannot issue its own bonds or engage in open market operations. Issuing government debt - in the form of national Eurobonds - is left entirely to the individual member states who must sell them on the financial markets; until quite recently, the ECB could not even purchase national bonds.1 Indeed, for the ECB even to hold these as collateral against its short-term liquidity operations, national bonds must be well-viewed by the main credit rating agencies (CRAs). In the words of Thomas Palley (2011), '...the euro's architecture makes the bond market master of national governments. Given the dominance of neoliberal thinking, this was an intended outcome of the euro's design.' Misleading view While national exchange rate and monetary policies ceased to exist and EA regional exchange rate and monetary policies were also impaired, the general view is that fiscal policy, at both national and regional levels, survived the euro construct. But such a view is also misleading. Although there is a European budget, there is no EA or European Treasury. And because the European budget amounts to only 1% of the region's GDP, and must be balanced annually by law, it cannot be used as a counter-cyclical instrument. Apart from its small 'structural fund', the budget cannot be used either to effect transfers between rich and poor of the union.2 Famously, the decision
to exclude fiscal policy from the EU or EA remit was one of the 'great
compromise' conditions insisted on by Germany during the Delors Committee
negotiations culminating in the (1992) Maastricht Treaty.3 Instead,
national governments agreed to be bound by the twin rules - initially
meant as qualifying conditions for euro-access but set in concrete in
the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP) inserted into the 1997 Amsterdam
Treaty - that government annual budget deficits must not exceed 3% and
a national debt ceiling equivalent to no more than 60% of GDP must be
observed. Admittedly, examples of violation of the national budget constraints
can be cited for either large countries like More crucially, debates
about the SGP or, more recently, its folding into the future ESM, tend
to overlook the underlying constraint imposed by a common currency arrangement
without common or federal government. Fiscal policy becomes effectively
dependent on the performance of the external sector and the financial
behaviour of the private sector. As shown elsewhere (Izurieta 2001,
2003; Bell 2003; Godley and Lavoie 2007), a country tied by common currency
that faces an external shock can only have two policy options: a contractionary
spending adjustment which causes chronic levels of unemployment, or
a fiscal stimulus to regain employment losses at the cost of triggering
a financial crisis down the road. Beyond the analytics of fully consistent
stock/flow analytical models as those cited, the reason is simple: unable
to exercise exchange rate or monetary policy, a country in distress
without recourse to federal transfers or a lender-of-last-resort is
at the mercy of the private market to finance its debt, the accumulated
costs of which add to ever-increasing deficits. The large and obviously
unaffordable borrowing costs of Effect of structural rigidities This analysis runs counter to the common belief that economies are self-adjusting mechanisms and therefore that, faced with an external shock, a one-off adjustment triggers a response sufficient to absorb the shock and bring the country back to a steady state. But in the real world, structural rigidities often prevail, and underlying conditions tend to pull economies in diverging directions rather than towards a textbook-familiar steady state equilibrium. The proposition of divergent underlying conditions is nowhere more obvious than in the construct under which the EA was created, and is an essential part of the explanation why the euro project is flawed. In a number of contributions, Flassbeck (2007, 2005, 2000) points to the inadequacy of real exchange rate regimes driving unsustainable external positions of trading partners in the global economy. More specifically, referring to the EA, Flassbeck questions 'the long run viability of a monetary system with absolutely fixed nominal exchange rates but dramatically divergent real exchange rates' (2007: 43). After carefully dissecting the asymmetries created in the two Germanys after reunification, he singles out the tremendous pressure that German policymakers placed on trade unions to accept wage restraint in order for the country to 'regain international competitiveness' (the 'Bndnis fr Arbeit' agreement of 1996). The tendency towards
wage repression that started in the mid-1990s was aided by the fact
that other European trading partners used the D-mark as an anchor to
facilitate their smooth entry into the euro. It was this that prevented
the domestic currency appreciation warranted by the deceleration of
unit labour costs in the main surplus country, To many observers, an easy remedy would have been adopting a similar pace of wage disinflation throughout the EA. This is the main motive behind calls for 'labour market flexibility' that dominated the policy discourse in the EA in the years prior to the current crisis. But if it is difficult to overlook the socio-economic consequences of wages lagging well behind labour productivity in a single country, it seems even more incongruous to ignore the fact that wage repression for the entire region imparts a recessionary bias to all. In the absence of
nominal exchange rate adjustment at the national level (precluded by
the common currency), trade imbalances cannot be solved by means of
'internal devaluation', i.e., wage repression at the periphery. Just
as the China-US trade imbalance is best resolved by increasing aggregate
demand in Club-Med countries not a problem It follows that highlighting fiscal irresponsibility in the Club-Med countries as the source of the crisis is beside the point. Such a simplistic argument is negated by the basic national accounting identity that says that the sum of public and private financial balances of a country must exactly equal the external balance. As long as net export performance is driven by loss of competitiveness resulting from wage repression elsewhere in a common currency area (and import requirements and transfers are somehow correlated with the growth of output), and as long as the private sector as a whole determines its own net financial balance (net acquisition of financial assets) for reasons of its own, then the net financial position of the public sector is determined down to the last penny.4 In other words, if GDP tends to contract because of adverse trade performance and if private sector saving represents yet another leakage from the circular flow of income, a proactive fiscal deficit will be needed to maintain the pace of economic growth. A conservative budget merely adds to the contractionary tendencies while alleviating the trade imbalance. A contrasting case
is that of Clearly, the tremendous shock caused by the great recession has triggered a downward shift in the external position of these countries, as well as the rapid accumulation of public sector debt as governments rushed into bailing out the financial system to avoid a financial meltdown. Under the prevailing structural rigidities described above, it is no surprise that external deficit countries, if left to the mercy of 'the markets', are now threatened by a severe and protracted recession. Policy action required Policy action is necessary
if these trade imbalances are gradually to disappear. Crucially, labour
productivity must increase faster in the deficit countries than in the
surplus countries, an aim difficult to achieve unless proactive fiscal
policy and infrastructure investment trigger a modernising wave of 'crowding
in' private investment. This means that Three conclusions follow from the above analysis. First, a common currency system will fail unless sustained by an active central bank, a common fiscal policy and common labour policy. The EA system will either break down under the pressure of social unrest or because of a debt explosion and ensuing sovereign debt crisis. Second, wage repression
at the centre is an essential component of the euro crisis. Finally, a reasonably
egalitarian income distribution reached through a common labour policy
- where the distribution of productivity gains is agreed upon - must
be an essential feature of stable long-run prosperity. The 'wage flexibility'
framework peddled by Without effective supranational fiscal and labour authorities and a fully functional central bank, the EA cannot resolve these problems - even if the contradictions are internally suppressed or else transferred to the rest of the world via the real exchange rate. George Irvin is at the School of Oriental and African Studies, University of London, and Alex Izurieta is at the Development Policy and Analysis Division of the UN Department of Economic and Social Affairs and also at the Cambridge Endowment for Research in Finance, University of Cambridge. This article was first published in the Economic & Political Weekly (August 6, 2011) and is reproduced here with the kind permission of the authors. Views expressed in this article do not necessarily represent those of the United Nations. Notes 1 During the recent credit crisis, the ECB has purchased national Eurobonds, but its holdings are tiny compared to (say) US holdings of its own (say) Treasury bonds. 2 The notion of a union budget which could be used counter-cyclically was originally raised by MacDougall D and Commission of the European Communities (1977); more recently it has been revived by Goodhart (2007). 3 For critiques,
see Irvin (2007), 4 See Godley and
Izurieta (2004) for the conceptual framework, as well as Galbraith (2009)
for its validation in the macroeconomic analysis of the 5 Although income distribution appears to be more egalitarian in the EU than the US when looking at individual member states, the same is not true of income distribution with Europe taken as a whole - as Galbraith (2009) has rightly noted. References Buiter, W, G Corsetti
and N Roubini (1993): 'Excessive Deficits: Sense and Nonsense in the
Treaty of Flassbeck, H (2000): 'Wanted: An International Exchange Rate Regime - The Missed Lesson of the Financial Crisis', IPG - International Politics and Society, 3/2000. - (2005): 'Exchange
Rate Management in Developing Countries: The Need for a Multilateral
Solution', in B Fritz and M Metzger (eds.), New Issues in Regional Monetary
Coordination ( - (2007): 'Wage Divergences
in Euroland: Explosive in the Making', in J Bibow and A Terzi (eds.),
Euroland and the World Economy: Global Player or Global Drag? ( Galbraith, JK (2009):
The Godley, W (1992):
' Godley, W and A Izurieta
(2004): 'Balances, Imbalances and Fiscal Targets: A New Godley, W and M Lavoie
(2007): 'A Simple Model of Three Economies with Two Currencies: The
Eurozone and the Goodhart, CAE (2007):
'Replacing the Stability and Growth Pact', in J Bibow and A Terzi (eds.),
Euroland and the World Economy: Global Player or Global Drag? ( Irvin, G (2007): Regaining
Europe: An Economic Agenda for the 21st Century ( Izurieta, A (2001):
'Can Countries under a Common Currency Conduct Their Own Fiscal Policy?',
Levy Economics Institute of - (2003): 'Dollarisation
as a Tight Rein on the Fiscal Stance', in LP Rochon and M Seccareccia
(eds.), Dollarisation: Lessons from Europe and the MacDougall, D et al
(1977): Report of the Study Group on the Role of Public Finance in European
Integration ( Palley, T (2011): 'Monetary Union Stability: The Need for a Government Banker and the Case for a European Public Finance Authority', Institut fur Makrokonomie und Konjunkturforschung Working Paper 02/2011. Available at http:// www.networkideas.org/alt/jul2011/Monetary_ Union.pdf (last visited on 18 July 2011). Whyte, P (2010): 'Why
*Third World Resurgence No. 253, September 2011, pp 12-15 |
||
|