|
||
|
||
Microfinance: Profiting from the poor While advocates of microfinance often make exaggerated claims about its capacity to reduce poverty, there is no denying that it has a role to play. However, as some recent scandals involving microfinance institutions have revealed, there is a need for microfinance to be properly regulated. Kavaljit Singh THE
massive investments by private equity firms coupled with an initial
public offer (IPO) by SKS Microfinance have ignited a debate about the
ethics and objectives of microfinance institutions (MFIs) in SKS
Microfinance, the largest MFI in According to media reports, the original promoters of SKS Microfinance have sold part of their stake to a hedge fund, thereby making a 12-fold profit even before the IPO. This shrewd act by promoters and top management not merely raises doubts about their long-term commitment but, more importantly, calls into question the real motives of promoters who have become instant millionaires while their borrowers remain desperately poor. Though initially started by women's groups and non-governmental organisations (NGOs) to empower poor people at local level, microfinance is no longer a micro or local phenomenon. Globally, the microfinance industry controls over $50 billion in assets. In
To
private equity funds, the microfinance business in Unlike
commercial banks, MFIs are presently not regulated and supervised by
the Reserve Bank of One of the main reasons cited by some MFIs for charging high interest rates is that their administrative costs are higher than those of commercial banks. Indeed, delivery of small loans to people living in remote areas entails higher administrative costs. But such costs could be substantially offset by economies of scale, which, unfortunately, has not happened in most cases. Several large MFIs still charge abusively high interest rates despite their operations having increased manifold. The
other argument that greater competition among MFIs will lead to lower
interest rates is yet to be demonstrated in It would be erroneous to draw an analogy with any other industry or services because the raison d'etre of MFIs is to serve poor people and promote financial inclusion. The higher interest rates charged by MFIs place an unreasonable burden on poor borrowers. Why should poor borrowers pay the price for the inefficiencies of MFIs? Why should poor borrowers be exploited in the name of promoting financial inclusion? What about social and developmental objectives of MFIs? No one is arguing that MFIs should seek subsidies from donors to serve their clients. Rather they should pursue financial sustainability by removing operational inefficiencies and charging interest rates just high enough to cover the lending costs. There
are many MFIs in Throughout the world, MFIs are drawing greater public attention. In 2007, Banco Compartamos, a Mexican MFI, issued an IPO and consequently its original investors became instant millionaires. They received $450 million for selling 30% ownership of the institution. The reason for such a high valuation of Banco Compartamos was that it had been generating super profits (returns on equity at 55%), arising out of very high interest charges at 85% a year to poor borrowers. In September 2009, CARE (a US-based humanitarian aid agency) pocketed $74 million when it sold a 77% stake in a Peruvian MFI, Financiera Edyficar, to a local bank. In
There are many instances of aggressive lending by MFIs with negative outcomes. In 2005, many poor borrowers (mostly women) landed themselves in a spiral of indebtedness in Andhra Pradesh. For these borrowers, MFIs were no better than traditional moneylenders as they charged exorbitant rates of interest (80% and above). Some MFIs also used coercive methods of loan recovery that were humiliating to women borrowers, including making them stand in the hot sun and locking up their homes. Some borrowers reportedly committed suicide in Andhra Pradesh as they were unable to bear the harassment by MFIs. All
these recent instances suggest that lending by MFIs could also be counter-productive
if not properly regulated. In some countries, legislated interest rate
caps for MFIs are under discussion. The RBI should examine the relevance
of interest rate caps and other measures, particularly for large MFIs
in Due to growing public concern, efforts are being made to launch a self-regulation code to discipline MFIs. But the self-regulation code is voluntary and non-binding and therefore cannot stop greedy promoters from reckless profiteering. At best, the code can complement regulatory measures. As
the numbers of MFIs in Rather
than becoming institutional moneylenders, MFIs should give strong competition
to traditional moneylenders in Kavaljit
Singh works with the Public Interest Research Centre in *Third World Resurgence No. 236, April 2010, pp 3-4 |
||
|